Do We Really Need China’s Rapid Growth?
The mood at the World Economic Forum this week in Tianjin has been
a study in contrasts — bullish foreigners and gloomy Chinese.
As the FT’s Jamil Anderlini reports:
In quiet conversations and background chats with Chinese
officials and analysts about the state of things in China, the
tone of despondency and cynicism was pervasive while the views of
international attendees on China were generally bullish and
upbeat.
This divergence has almost certainly been going on for some time.
Judging from the markets alone, the rest of the world cheers any
signs of resurgent growth in China, or a stimulus package that
might make such a thing happen. Meanwhile the authorities have
been signalling their discomfort with the side effects of the
2008-2009 stimulus for well over a year now. The property bubble
which the stimulus helped inflate has been a particular concern,
with curbs targeted at dampening down speculation first being
introduced in 2010.
The property bubble, along with the surge in infrastructure
spending, has helped to further push China’s economy in an
unusually unbalanced direction, in which the majority of GDP is
made up of investment while consumption’s share of GDP is lower
than that seen in just about any other country, ever.
This rarely seems to bother the pundits, strategists and investors
who tend to see high GDP growth as a good thing, regardless of
what that growth is composed of.
In fact, the Chinese authorities take the challenge of rebalancing
far more seriously than do foreign investors, who tend to jump at
any sign of stimulus even when it will clearly exacerbate the
already extreme imbalance. Even in his big speech in Tianjin this
week clearly promising action on growth, Premier Wen emphasised
that point:
Although growth is slowing down, it is more stable. We will
give greater priority to stabilising and maintaining the
continuity and stability of our policies.
Or as an editorial from Xinhua today, titled “Less speed, but no
more stimulus” puts it:
Many have expected the government to announce an aggressive
plan, similar to the 4 trillion yuan ($632 billion) stimulus
package issued in 2008, to keep the economy from stalling for a
second time.
The government has been cautious about making any bold moves.
However, its hesitation should be seen as a pragmatic move, as
authorities are aware of the limitations of a possible stimulus
plan and do not want to upset the timing regarding the rebalancing
of the economy.
There’s a tonne of other examples out there where Chinese leaders
have talked about the need for rebalance, if you want to look for
them.
Let’s also not forget that the central government lowered its own
growth target this year to 7.5 per cent, after years at 8 per
cent. But what about all this doubling-down on imbalance we’ve
been pointing out over the past few months? The Chinese government
is in a quandary because of the many powerful figures (not least
within their own leadership) who have benefitted greatly from the
imbalanced status quo. (More about this later.)
So why the obsession with GDP growth at double-digits, or close to
double digits? Why has there been so much denial and disbelief
that annual GDP growth might fall below 8 per cent, and perhaps
more — and stay there for years?
In fact, why the obsession with GDP at all? It comes down, very
broadly, to maintaining stability in undemocratic China: the
bargain that there won’t be a widescale revolt against the
authorities as long as enough people feel their wealth is growing.
The magic growth rate below which unemployment and social unrest
become problems is somewhere around 5 to 7 per cent, depending on
whom you ask and what length of time you are talking about.
However Michael Pettis is not so sure. In his latest newsletter,
he repeats his assertion that slower economic growth is absolutely
necessary for China to rebalance its economy. Growing GDP at the
same rate while increasing the consumption or household income
share of GDP would require the latter to rise at a phenomenal
rate.
It sounds dire to say that China’s growth has to slow and probably
by several percentage points, as Pettis believes. But he points
out the positive side of this: in order to rebalance, household
income will have to grow faster than GDP. So even if GDP falls to
3 or 4 per cent — unimaginable to many — household income, says
Pettis, would grow at 5 to 6 per cent a year in a rebalancing
scenario.
As he explains:
This, and not reported GDP, is what really matters. Chinese
households, like those in the rest of the world, are not so much
concerned with per capita GDP as with changes in their disposable
household income and in their wealth. If China rebalances
successfully there is no reason household income growth should
collapse, even as GDP growth rates slow significantly. This is a
big “if”, of course, and requires that Beijing understand the
risks, and forces through what will be politically difficult
measures, but so far it seems that they do.
What about the rest of the world, desperate for its “engine of
global growth” to stay resiliant? Even that is overstated, says
Pettis:
Nor is rebalancing bad for the rest of the world (although as
I wrote in the last issue of this newsletter copper, iron, and
other hard commodity producers will suffer tremendously). The idea
that China is the global engine of growth is based on confused
arithmetic – it is simply the largest arithmetical component of
global growth. What the world needs from China is not more growth.
It needs more net demand, and a rebalancing China, even with much
slower growth, will provide just that.
Not that rebalancing will be at all easy. Pettis argues there are
three ways to do it:
Revalue the renminbi (so that households aren’t penalised by
expensive imports)
Raise interest rates (this will make the cost of capital more
expensive, hurting capital-intensive manufacturers, but help
middle-class savers)
Raise wages (this will hurt more labour-intensive
manufacturers but will, obviously, help households, especially the
poorer ones).
Which path China chooses to follow should be seen by the world
primarily as something that affects the way the costs and benefits
of rebalancing are distributed domestically. For the sake of more
sustainable and equitable long-term growth, and in the interests
of economic efficiency, it is almost certainly much better for
China and the world if Beijing raises interest rates than if it
revalues the RMB, but since raising interest rates is likely to be
opposed by the very powerful groups that benefit from excessively
cheap capital, Beijing may instead put more focus on raising
wages, which comes mainly at the detriment of economically
efficient but politically weak small and medium enterprises and
service industries.
Which should be reassuring for all those countries who feel miffed
about cheap Chinese exports.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.